The Value of Climate Amenities: Evidence from US Migration Decisions

Date

Jan. 2, 2013

Authors

Paramita Sinha and Maureen L. Cropper

Publication

Working Paper

Reading time

2 minutes
We value climate amenities by estimating a discrete location choice model for households that changed metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) between 1995 and 2000. The utility of each MSA depends on location-specific amenities, earnings opportunities, housing costs, and the cost of moving to the MSA from the household’s 1995 location. We use the estimated trade-off between wages and climate amenities to value changes in mean winter and summer temperatures. At median temperatures for 1970 to 2000, a 1°F increase in winter temperature is worth less than a 1° decrease in summer temperature; however, the reverse is true at winter temperatures below 25°F. These results imply an average welfare loss of 2.7 percent of household income in 2020 to 2050 under the B1 (climate-friendly) scenario from the special report on emissions scenarios (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change 2000), although some cities in the Northeast and Midwest benefit. Under the A2 (more extreme) scenario, households in 25 of 26 cities suffer an average welfare loss equal to 5 percent of income.

Earnings, housing, and other location-specific amenities are among the factors that influence a household’s decision to settle in a given area. Climate, too, plays a role, and as average temperatures rise, the amenity value of climate—what people are willing to pay to experience warmer winters or to avoid hotter summers—has become an important consideration for crafting greenhouse gas mitigation policies and understanding estimates of the costs of damages associated with climate change.

In a new RFF discussion paper, “The Value of Climate Amenities: Evidence from US Migration Decisions,” Paramita Sinha, of RTI International, and co-author RFF Senior Fellow Maureen Cropper value climate amenities, estimating the willingness to pay (WTP) of recently moved households to avoid cold winter temperatures and hot summer temperatures. They find that people are willing to pay more to decrease summer temperatures by 1°F than to increase winter temperatures by the same factor. At temperatures below 25°F, however, they find the reverse to be true.

Cropper and Sinha use these estimates to value changes in mean summer and winter temperature over the period 2020 to 2050 for 26 US cities. Under a “climate-friendly” projection based on an Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) report on emissions scenarios, both summer and winter temperatures will increase, on average, by 3.3°F. Averaged across all cities, what people are willing to pay to avoid this increase in temperature is about 2.7 percent of income, according to the authors. Under the IPCC’s more extreme scenario, households in 25 of 26 cities suffer an average income loss of about 5 percent, assuming they do not move in response to changes in temperature.

The economic impact of climate amenities cannot be overlooked, conclude the authors: “Estimates for the United States of market-based damages associated with climate change have typically been in the range of 1 percent of gross domestic product for an increase in mean temperature of 2°C [according to the National Research Council]. Our results suggest that the amenity value of climate could significantly increase estimates of climate damages, even for moderate temperature increases.”

Authors

Related Content